nonmarginal price changes, in general. Consequently, incidence analysis
using the change-in-relative-prices measure often concludes the formal an-
alysis with the price changes. The link to consumer's welfare is then simply
presented in heuristic terms, in the form of general statements about who
gains and who loses (with many consumers).
In summary, then, the theory of tax incidence presents a quandary even
for simple one-consumer-equivalent economies. Despite the obvious motiv-
ation for developing empirical measures of tax incidence, there appear to be
no obvious candidates for the task unless production technology is linear.
With general technologies, unambiguous measures of welfare loss involve
compensated equilibria that cannot be observed in practice, and observed tax
and price vectors oVer at best only intuitive guidance to welfare losses. As a
practical matter, economists may have to be content with measures of price
changes in response to diVerent sets of taxes that leave the government
budget surplus unchanged, especially given that production technologies
are general and not linear.
The only Wrm conclusion one can draw is that if the incidence of a given
set of taxes is to have any meaning in a general equilibrium context, tax
incidence must be deWned in such a way as to render the impact of a tax only
indirectly relevant to the incidence measure. Tax revenues (or the resulting
budget surplus) from distorting taxes must be returned lump sum to the
consumer to have a well-deWned problem focusing on a single tax. The actual
tax payment can aVect incidence only through its inXuence on the amount
that market prices change in response to the tax. Regardless of whether one
chooses the income compensation or change-in-relative-price approach, the
Wnal incidence measure is fully determined by the resulting changes in the
general equilibrium price vectors.
THE EQUIVALENCE OF GENERAL TAXES
Although the income compensation and change-in-actual-price measures of
incidence approach the problem from diVerent perspectives, they each imply
the following important result: In a perfectly competitive, proWtless economy,
in which tax revenues (or the budget surplus) are always returned lump sum,
any two sets of taxes have identical incidence if they generate the same
changes in relative prices.
Consider, Wrst, the relative price measure of incidence. If production is
proWtless and tax revenues are returned to the consumers, actual consumer
demands (factors suppliers) are functions only of relative prices. Producers'
supply (input demand) relationships are also functions only of relative prices.
Therefore, two sets of taxes that generate the same vector of relative prices
generate the same with-tax general equilibrium. Consequently, they must
have the same incidence by the relative price criterion.
540 THE EQUIVALENCE OF GENERAL TAXES
Get Public Finance, 2nd Edition now with the O’Reilly learning platform.
O’Reilly members experience books, live events, courses curated by job role, and more from O’Reilly and nearly 200 top publishers.