LUMP-SUM REDISTRIBUTIONS AND PUBLIC SECTOR THEORY
Are lump-sum redistributions a feasible policy tool for the government? This
may appear to be a relatively uninteresting question. One is tempted to
answer: ``Probably not, but even if they are feasible it hardly matters because
few governments use lump-sum taxes and transfers. For instance, no major
U.S. tax or transfer program is lump sum.'' All this is true, yet it is hard to
imagine a more important question for normative public sector theory. The
answer has a dramatic impact on all normative policy prescriptions in every
area of public sector analysis, whether they be directed at distributional or
allocational problems. In public sector theory, lump-sum redistributions
stand at the border between Wrst-best and second-best analysis.
The issue is not so much the existence of lump-sum redistributions.
Lump-sum tax and transfer programs are easy enough to describe. Poll
taxes have occasionally been used as revenue sources and they are certainly
lump sum from an economic perspective. On the transfer side, many coun-
tries have instituted per-person demogrants (e.g., Canada, which provides a
grant to all the elderly). The United States has not used demogrants, but it
may soon. In his 1996 presidential election campaign, Robert Dole proposed
a $500 per child refundable tax credit under the federal personal income tax.
It might be argued that decisions on family size are essentially economic and
would inXuence the amount of transfer received. If so, then tax credits and
demogrants to children are not strictly lump sum, although the legislation
could be drafted such that only children already living at the time of passage
would receive the transfers.
The mere existence of lump-sum taxes and transfers is not enough,
however, to render them feasible policy tools in the pursuit of equity. The
lump-sum taxes and transfers must be Xexible enough so that they can be
designed to satisfy the interpersonal equity conditions for social welfare
maximization, and this is a very tall order indeed. To be eVective, the taxes
and transfers would almost certainly have to be related to consumption or
income or wealth in order to distinguish the haves from the have nots, but
then it is doubtful that they would be lump sum.
Income taxes were thought to be essentially lump sum before 1970,
because empirical research had been unable to discover any relationship
between income tax rates and either work eVort or saving. Research since
then, employing detailed micro data sets and sophisticated microeconometric
techniques, suggests that labor supply does respond to changes in after-tax
wages, certainly the female labor supply. The evidence on saving behavior is
more mixed, but saving also appears to respond somewhat to changes in
after-tax rates of return.
1
In any event, no one today believes that income-
1
For an excellent review of the early empirical studies on labor supply and savings
elasticities, see M. Boskin, ``On Some Recent Econometric Research in Public Finance,'' AEA
66 LUMP-SUM REDISTRIBUTIONS AND PUBLIC SECTOR THEORY

Get Public Finance, 2nd Edition now with the O’Reilly learning platform.

O’Reilly members experience books, live events, courses curated by job role, and more from O’Reilly and nearly 200 top publishers.