criterion for taxes and transfers in a Wrst-best policy environment. They
represent, simultaneously, a complete prescription for the optimal distribu-
tion of income and for the optimal redistribution of income when starting
from a nonoptimal distribution.
Having considered how taxes and transfers help achieve the pareto-
optimal and interpersonal equity conditions of Wrst-best social welfare maxi-
mization, mainstream public sector theory has nothing more to say about
Wrst-best tax policy.
PUBLIC CHOICE AND PARETO-OPTIMAL REDISTRIBUTION
The policy implications associated with the interpersonal equity conditions
are perhaps the least convincing component of the mainstream Wrst-best
theory. On the one hand, any tax or transfer that is related to an individual's
well being, such as a personal income tax or a means-tested transfer payment,
is unlikely to be lump sum. On the other hand, the interpersonal equity
conditions rely on the social welfare function which, although a useful
analytical construct, is problematic in the extreme as a practical guide to
distributional policies. As noted in Chapter 3, there is no convincing theory
to determine what the marginal social welfare weights should be, and Arrow
proved that a democratic society may not be able to articulate a consistent
social welfare function when individuals disagree about the appropriate
weights.
Mainstream public sector economists have responded to the diYculties
of the social welfare function in one of two ways, for the most part. The Wrst
might be called the technocractic response, most closely associated with
Paul Samuelson. The idea here is to concede that economic theory has
nothing useful to say about the form of the social welfare function. At the
same time, an operative social welfare function undoubtedly exists; the
ruling politicians are setting their policies with some set of marginal social
welfare weights in mind. Therefore, simply ask the policymakers what their
social welfare function is and then tell them what the optimal policies are
given that function. Economists can solve constrained optimum problems
once they know what the objective function is. The second mainstream
response, and the more common one, is to retain the social welfare function
in normative analysis but use a Xexible form of the function that permits a
wide range of social welfare weights. The Atkinson and Jorgenson social
welfare functions described in Chapter 4 are examples. They each employ
Atkinson's aversion-to-inequality parameter, which admits the full range
of social welfare weights that people are likely to prefer, from utilitarian
indiVerence to Rawlsian egalitarianism. The idea behind the Xexible-
form approach is to see how optimal policies vary with the social welfare
weights.
10. THE FIRST-BEST THEORY OF TAXATION 309
Get Public Finance, 2nd Edition now with the O’Reilly learning platform.
O’Reilly members experience books, live events, courses curated by job role, and more from O’Reilly and nearly 200 top publishers.