constant returns to scale. Even the government is assumed to transact at the
competitive producer prices to the extent it buys and sells inputs and outputs.
A second-best model might posit constraints in the form of noncompetitive
behavior in a small subset of markets, but the underlying market economy is
almost always competitive. Second-best results may not have competitive
interpretations, but the majority of models used to date have been competi-
tive through and through.
The newer literature on private information is somewhat of an exception
because it applies the techniques of game theory, and the games being played
may not occur in a market setting. Even so, the decentralized nature of the
competitive market has a correspondence in the public sector allocation
mechanisms that honor the revelation principle. A standard requirement of
truth-revealing mechanisms is that individuals have no control over their
opportunity sets. The public sector mechanisms must be decentralizable in
this sense.
In summary, although second-best theory has severely challenged all
Wrst-best policy rules, it has taken only the smallest, most hesitant steps
away from the highly stylized Wrst-best policy environment. Second-best
analysis is more realistic, but only slightly so.
PREVIEW OF PART III
With these reXections in mind, we will begin our second-best analysis with the
allocational theory of taxation, thereby reversing the order of presentation in
Part II. This happens to coincide with the historical development of second-
best theory, but that is really beside the point. There are two good analytical
reasons for considering tax theory Wrst.
One is that second-best tax theory is inherently simpler than second-best
expenditure theory, in this sense. Public expenditure theory requires the
speciWcation of a distinct problem (e.g., an externality) and one or more
distinct constraints (e.g., distorting taxation), whereas tax theory requires
only the speciWcation of a constraint. Saying that all taxes must be distorting
is at once an additional constraint on the system and the source of the
problem being analyzed in tax theory. Consequently, problems in tax theory
can be analyzed with much simpler general equilibrium models. This is an
important advantage. Second-best models speciWed in terms of prices are
quite diVerent from the Wrst-best quantity model of Part II, enough so that it
pays to begin the analysis as simply as possible. Thus, the initial chapters on
tax theory have two goals. Their main purpose is to demonstrate some
important theorems in the allocational theory of taxation, but they also
serve as an introduction to second-best methodology.
Second-best tax theory also logically precedes public expenditure theory,
so long as distorting taxes are one of the policy constraints. Having studied
12. INTRODUCTION TO SECOND-BEST ANALYSIS 397

Get Public Finance, 2nd Edition now with the O’Reilly learning platform.

O’Reilly members experience books, live events, courses curated by job role, and more from O’Reilly and nearly 200 top publishers.