15
TAXATION UNDER
ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION
LUMP-SUM REDISTRIBUTIONS AND PRIVATE INFORMATION
REDISTRIBUTION THROUGH COMMODITY TAXATION
OPTIMAL TAXATION, PRIVATE INFORMATION, AND
SELF-SELECTION CONSTRAINTS
Elements of the Model
Pareto-Efficient Taxation
An Extension: The Direct-Indirect Tax Mix
OPTIMAL INCOME TAXATION
The Shape of the Tax Schedule
Concluding Observations
TAX EVASION
Increasing the Penalty
Increasing Monitoring
Revenue-Raising Strategies
Tax Amnesties
CONCLUDING REMARKS
The text so far has ignored an important market imperfection, the
presence of private or asymmetric information. Chapter 15 explores the
implications of asymmetric information on taxation, and later chapters
extend the analysis to transfer payments and other public expenditures.
Analysis under the assumption of asymmetric information is inherently
second best because Wrst-best analysis requires that agents have perfect infor-
mation about everything relevant to their economic decisions and exchanges.
The problem of asymmetric information has been a focal point of public
sector analysis for the past 15 or 20 years, just as it has been in almost all Welds
of economics. The recent interest in asymmetric information is understand-
able, Wrst and foremost because it is so common. Agents often possess private
information about themselves that other agents, including the government,
do not or cannot know, at least not without undertaking considerable eVort
485
and cost to monitor behavior. In addition, optimizing agents have obvious
incentives to exploit private information to their own advantage, and econo-
mists quite naturally assume they will do so to the fullest extent possible.
Finally, the assumption of asymmetric information often produces results
that are very diVerent from those obtained under the assumption of perfect
information. This has been especially true in public sector economics.
Regarding the theory of taxation, old standards such as the Ramsey tax
rule for one-consumer equivalent economies or the Diamond±Mirrlees
many-person tax rule are no longer prescriptions for optimal taxation
under private information. This is so even if the government can in principle
tax (almost) everything as the Ramsey and Diamond±Mirrlees models
assume. In fact, governments may be quite restricted in what they can tax
under private information. They may not have suYcient information about
some economic variables to use them as a tax base. What can the government
tax? is an important policy question in a world of private information. A Wnal
point is that private information can severely constrain a government's
ability to redistribute purchasing power through taxes and transfers.
The last comment on redistribution points to a special diYculty with
private information: It is not simply a technological or structural imper-
fection. Rather, it has certain uncomfortable behavioral characteristics that
are absent from other market imperfections such as distorting taxes, or
monopoly power, or legislated budget constraints. Agents who exploit pri-
vate information for their own self-interest at the expense of broader social
goals tear at the fabric of society. They violate the spirit of good citizenship
that is necessary to hold a society together. An obvious example is people
who evade paying taxes that would have been transferred to the poor.
1
Such behavior also strikes at the foundations of normative public sector
theory. What is normative theory to make of the tax evaders, especially when
the norms include a concern for equity as well as eYciency? In formal terms,
should the social welfare function give dishonest taxpayers the same ethical
weight as honest taxpayers who could also exploit private information but do
not? If unequal weights are chosen, how unequal should they be? Should the
dishonest receive zero weight? If the dishonest are to receive a positive weight,
should society be expected to spend its scare resources on monitoring their
behavior or on punishing them? Should the government signiWcantly alter its
tax policies to discourage dishonest behavior? These are diYcult, open ques-
tions that have profound implications for any normative analysis. DiVerent
answers can lead to very diVerent policy recommendations.
As it happens, much of the recent normative public sector analysis has
continued the long-established tradition of using the equal-weight utilitarian
1
The same could be said of agents who exploit monopoly power, but their behavior is not
diVerent in kind from proWt maximizing under perfect competition, unlike the distinction
between honest and dishonest taxpayers. It is also less secretive than something like tax evasion.
486 TAXATION UNDER ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION
Get Public Finance, 2nd Edition now with the O’Reilly learning platform.
O’Reilly members experience books, live events, courses curated by job role, and more from O’Reilly and nearly 200 top publishers.