prevents an analysis of the eVect of rationing the X
i
among diVerent con-
sumers. Removing any one of these assumptions would require signiWcant
modiWcations in the government production-tax model of Chapter 22. None-
theless, the model as it stands remains a fairly general description of govern-
ment policy in a second-best environment. It would appear to be applicable
to government hydroelectric projects in which some of the beneWts are sold
(electricity) while others (recreational facilities) are given away even though
they are routinely marketed in other contexts.
We leave it to the reader to derive and interpret the Wrst-order conditions
for this model. The normative policy rules yield a number of interesting
conclusions. The existence of goods (factors) given away (drafted) does not
change either the optimal tax rules or the result that with optimal taxation
(and CRS in private production) the government should discount all
marketed inputs and outputs at their marginal rate of transformation (the
producer price). A diVerent discount rate does apply to all free goods and
drafted factors, however.
THE USE OF SHADOW PRICES FOR GOVERNMENT PROJECTS
The preceding sections discussed three problems commonly associated with
government projectsÐintangibles, lumpiness, and nonmarketed beneWts
(costs)Ðthat are unlikely to arise in private sector analysis. These problems
need not always occur, however. In many instances government projects
might be virtually identical to their private sector counterparts in the sense
that they represent marginal additions to capacity and all inputs and outputs
are bought and sold at competitive private sector prices.
22
Even when this
occurs, however, there are still substantial diVerences between the evalu-
ations of private and public sector costs and beneWts, as a general rule.
As noted above, competitive producer prices are the proper values to
attach to each unit of private inputs or outputs under these conditions, from
society's point of view. pDX is an appropriate gross beneWt measure for a
private project in either a Wrst- or second-best environment.
In contrast, Eq. (22.46), reproduced here as Eq. (26.16) (with a negative
sign, since B dL),
dB t
0
M
ij

E
1
p
ij
dt p
1
g
Z
p
0
t
0
M
ij
E
1

dZ (26:16)
gives the proper shadow prices for government inputs and outputs in the one-
consumer-equivalent, second-best economy of Chapter 22. The assumptions
about government producers that underly Eq. (26.16) are the same as for
private producers: The government buys and sells at competitive private
22
One may wonder why the government is involved in the production of these services, but
this is beside the point for cost±beneWt analysis.
800 THE USE OF SHADOW PRICES FOR GOVERNMENT PROJECTS

Get Public Finance, 2nd Edition now with the O’Reilly learning platform.

O’Reilly members experience books, live events, courses curated by job role, and more from O’Reilly and nearly 200 top publishers.