3. We saw that public policy is problematic in the case of individualized
consumption externalities because the government must design a set of H
corrective taxes, one for each of H people consuming the good. In contrast,
when the external eVect depends only on aggregate consumption a single tax
paid by all consumers can achieve the pareto-optimal conditions. The same
distinction applies for production externalities.
Because of these similarities, Chapter 7 presents only the aggregate
production externalities model. The aggregate model is by far the one most
widely used in policy applications, and it provides a simple analytical frame-
work for considering a number of policy implications that could have been
discussed in the preceding chapter but are especially intuitive in a production
framework. Most of the policy examples in Chapter 7 center on pollution
control, as industrial pollution is a particularly appropriate and important
application of the aggregate production externalities model. Chapter 8 then
discusses U.S. antipollution policy as an extended example incorporating
both production and consumption externalities.
Having analyzed aggregate production externalities and noted their
similarities with aggregate consumption externalities, the reader should have
no diYculty modeling other types of production externalities. The other pro-
duction cases are also closely analogous to their consumption counterparts.
THE CONDENSED MODEL FOR PRODUCTION EXTERNALITIES
The analysis of consumption externalities used a condensed version of the
general equilibrium model in Chapter 2 for its analytical framework of
the form:
max
X
ik

WU
h


s:t: F
P
H
i1
X
ik

0
where X
ik
was deWned as the consumption of good k by person i. The way in
which the X
ik
entered each person's utility function determined the appropri-
ate policy response by the government.
Production externalities can also be analyzed with a condensed version
of the full general equilibrium model, the only diVerence being that the model
must highlight possible interdependencies in production rather than in con-
sumption. To achieve this, we will ignore once again any notational distinc-
tion between goods and factors but deWne the arguments, X, in terms of
production. Let X
ji
good (factor) i supplied (demanded) by Wrm j, with
factors measured negatively, j 1, ...,J and i 1, ..., N. There are J
Wrms and N goods and factors.
206 THE CONDENSED MODEL FOR PRODUCTION EXTERNALITIES
Since we are now interested in production interrelationships, writing
production as a single production-possibilities frontier is no longer use-
ful. The model must retain the individual-Wrm production functions. De-
Wne f
k
 0 as the implicit production function for Wrm k, k 1, ...,
J.Write:
f
k
X
ji

0k 1, ...,J (7:1)
as the most general notation. This allows for the worst possible case of
individualized externalities, in which each of the J production relationships
has JN arguments: The production (use) of any of the N goods (factors) by
any of the J Wrms in the economy aVects every Wrm. In this model, each Wrm
could produce multiple outputs, rather than a single output as in the Chapter
2 model. The model also permits each good and factor to be produced,
although this is not necessary. J can be larger or smaller than N.
1
Analogous with consumption externalities, deWne a pure public good
(factor) as one for which:
qf
k
qX
ji
f
k
ji
6 0 all k, j 1, ...,J (7:2)
That is, production (use) of good (factor) i aVects all production relation-
ships on the margin no matter where activity i occurs. This is the worst case
described above. Similarly, a pure private good (factor) is one for which:
qf
k
qX
ji
f
k
ji
0k6 j(7:3)
Firm k's use or production of i aVects only itself on the margin. Production
with private goods and factors is represented notationally as f
k
X
ki
0,
analogous with the notation of Chapter 6.
The condensation occurs in the household sector of the Chapter 2 model.
Interrelationships among consumers are irrelevant to the study of production
externalities, so that it is no longer necessary to retain a many-consumer
economy along with the social welfare function to resolve distributional
questions. These could be retained, to be sure, but the existence of production
externalities does not alter any of the pareto-optimal consumption conditions
or the interpersonal equity social welfare conditions that are necessary for
reaching the Wrst-best bliss point. No loss of generality occurs, then by
assuming a one-consumer-equivalent economy in which the consumer
supplies all factors of production and receives all the produced goods
and services, providing it is understood that one-consumer equivalence arises
because the government is optimally redistributing lump sum to satisfy the
interpersonal equity conditions of social welfare maximization. Without this
1
J is much larger than N in actual economiesÐthe number of Wrms far exceeds the number
of goods and factors.
7. PRODUCTION EXTERNALITIES 207

Get Public Finance, 2nd Edition now with the O’Reilly learning platform.

O’Reilly members experience books, live events, courses curated by job role, and more from O’Reilly and nearly 200 top publishers.