A BRIEF HISTORY OF SECOND-BEST THEORY
Second-best theorizing swept into public sector economics to stay in the
1970s and has been at the forefront of the discipline ever since. The impetus
was provided by two seminal articles that appeared about ten years apart:
``The General Theory of Second-Best,'' by Archibald Lipsey and Kelvin
Lancaster, and ``Optimal Taxation and Public Production,'' by Peter Dia-
mond and James Mirrlees.
2
The two articles approached second-best analysis
from diVerent perspectives and each became a template for distinct branches
of the second-best literature that followed.
The Lipsey±Lansacter paper took the natural Wrst step away from the
Samuelson's Wrst-best general equilibrium model. Their model assumes that
price exceeds marginal cost in at least one market, either because of private
monopoly power or distorting government taxes, and that the government is
unwilling or unable to remove the distortion. Otherwise, the government has
as much freedom to act as it has in the Wrst-best model, including the ability to
redistribute income lump sum.
Lipsey and Lancaster were speciWcally interested in the following
question: Given maintained distortions in some markets, are the Wrst-best
pareto-optimal rules for other markets still consistent with social welfare
maximization? The answer turned out to be ``no'' in general, a result that
became known as the ``theorem of the second best.'' Subsequent research has
expanded their analysis to consider the eVects of maintained distortions on
Wrst-best public expenditure decision rules and on the welfare implications of
changing the pattern of distorting taxes. One can ask, for example, whether
substituting one set of distorting taxes for another while holding tax revenue
constant increases social welfare, given the existence of still other distortions.
These are issues of policy reform in a second-best environment, by now a huge
body of literature in the Lipsey±Lancaster mold.
The Diamond±Mirrlees model was also only one step removed from
Samuelson's Wrst-best model, but they asked a diVerent question from Lip-
sey±Lancaster. The only maintained restriction in their model is that the
2
R. Lipsey and K. Lancaster, ``The General Theory of Second-Best,'' Review of Economic
Studies, Vol. 24 (1), No. 63, pp. 1956±57; P. Diamond and J. Mirrlees, ``Optimal Taxation and
Public Production,'' American Economic Review, March, June 1971 (2 parts; Part I: Production
EYciency, Part II: Tax Rules). The Diamond/Mirrlees paper was completed in 1968 and widely
circulated as an MIT Working Paper. It was well known and widely cited by the time it was
published in 1971. Two other early articles are worth mentioning, one on production and one on
taxation: M. Boiteux, ``On the Management of Public Monopolies Subject to Budgetary Con-
straints,'' Journal of Economic Theory, September 1971 (Boiteux's article Wrst appeared in the
January 1956 Econometrica in French); and J. Stiglitz and P. Dasgupta, ``DiVerential Taxation,
Public Goods, and Economic EYciency,'' Review of Economic Studies, April 1971. These articles
are frequently referenced in the second-best literature. For an excellent (but diYcult) summary of
second-best methodology, see H. Green, ``Two Models of Optimal Pricing and Taxation,''
Oxford Economic Papers, November 1975.
390 A BRIEF HISTORY OF SECOND-BEST THEORY
Get Public Finance, 2nd Edition now with the O’Reilly learning platform.
O’Reilly members experience books, live events, courses curated by job role, and more from O’Reilly and nearly 200 top publishers.