13
THE SECOND-BEST THEORY OF
TAXATION IN ONE-CONSUMER
ECONOMIES WITH LINEAR
PRODUCTION TECHNOLOGY
GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM PRICE MODELS
THE MEASUREMENT OF LOSS FROM DISTORTING TAXES
The Geometry of Loss Measurement: Partial Equilibrium Analysis
The Geometry of Loss Measurement: General Equilibrium Analysis
The Analytics of General Equilibrium Loss Measurement
Policy Implications of the Loss Measures
THE OPTIMAL PATTERN OF COMMODITY TAXES
Policy Implications of the Optimal Tax Rule
SUBSTITUTIONS AMONG TAXES: IMPLICATIONS FOR
WELFARE LOSS
The Corlett and Hague Analysis
The second-best theory of taxation explores the eVects of distorting taxes
on social welfare. A distorting tax is one that prevents at least one of the Wrst-
best pareto-optimal conditions from holding; that is, it forces society inside
its Wrst-best utility-possibilities frontier. The Wrst-best pareto-optimal condi-
tions are equalities between marginal rates of substitutions and marginal
rates of transformation. As such, they require that agents face the same prices
in a market economy. Distorting taxes prevent the equalities from holding
because they force at least two economic agents in the same market to face
diVerent prices in an otherwise perfectly competitive economy. Virtually all
taxes actually employed by governments introduce some distortion into the
economy, whether they be sales, excise, income, or wealth taxes. (Transfer
payments are automatically included in the analysis because transfers are
analytically equivalent to negative taxes.)
Because tax distortion is deWned relative to pareto optimality, much of
the literature on second-best tax theory has treated it strictly as an allocational
399
issue, concerned only with questions of economic eYciency. Consequently,
the analysis often occurs within the context of one-consumer economies, a
simpliWcation that makes sense if one is willing to ignore distributional
concerns. As Chapter 12 noted, however, second-best analysis has shown
that allocational and distributional issues do not dichotomize in a second-
best environment without lump-sum taxes and transfers, thereby raising
questions about the policy relevance of considering the eYciency aspects of
distorting taxes independently from their distributional consequences. Prob-
ably no one today would recommend a set of taxes simply on the basis of
their eYciency properties. Nonetheless, it is analytically convenient to isolate
the eYciency eVects of taxes by using one-consumer economy models. We
can then consider the tax rules in many-person economies as combinations of
eYciency and distributional elements, with the latter represented by the social
welfare weights derived from an individualistic social welfare function. This is
the approach we will take in developing the second-best theory.
The theory of distorting taxation addresses three main questions, one
associated with welfare loss, another with optimality, and a third with tax
reform:
1. Welfare lossÐRelative to the Wrst-best optimum, what is the loss in
social welfare associated with any given set of distorting taxes (including a
single tax)? Harold Hotelling provided the Wrst rigorous analysis of this issue
in his 1938 article, ``The General Welfare in Relation to Problems of Tax-
ation and of Railway and Utility Rates.''
1
Arnold Harberger rekindled
interest in this question in two separate articles appearing in 1964, ``Taxation,
Resource Allocation and Welfare'' and ``The Measurement of Waste.''
2
By
now the literature is voluminous, with these three articles standing as the
seminal contributions.
2. OptimalityÐRelative to the Wrst-best optimum, what pattern of dis-
torting taxes minimizes the loss in social welfare for any given amount of tax
revenue the government might wish to raise? This question has been explored
under two separate assumptions: (a) that the government can tax all goods
and factors, and (b) that a subset of goods and factors must remain untaxed.
The study of optimal taxation under the Wrst assumption is commonly re-
ferred to as the optimal commodity tax problem, with seminal contributions
by Frank Ramsey in ``A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation'' (1927), and
Peter Diamond and James Mirrlees' ``Optimal Taxation and Public Produc-
1
H. Hotelling, ``The General Welfare in Relation to Problems of Taxation and of Railway
and Utility Rates,'' Econometrica, July 1938.
2
A. Harberger, ``Taxation, Resource Allocation and Welfare,'' in National Bureau of
Economic Research and the Brookings Institution, The Role of Direct and Indirect Taxes in the
Federal Revenue System, (Princeton University Press, Princeton N.J., 1964; A. Harberger, ``The
Measurement of Waste,'' American Economic Association Papers and Proceedings, May 1964. An
excellent recent reference for the early literature is J. Green and E. Sheshinski, ``Approximating
the EYciency Gains of Tax Reforms,'' Journal of Public Economics, April 1979.
400 THE SECOND-BEST THEORY OF TAXATION IN ONE-CONSUMER ECONOMIES

Get Public Finance, 2nd Edition now with the O’Reilly learning platform.

O’Reilly members experience books, live events, courses curated by job role, and more from O’Reilly and nearly 200 top publishers.