3. They also considered the welfare loss of moving to uniform taxes from
the optimal tax rates, with the loss deWned as the amount that the government
would have to lower its revenue to maintain social welfare at its value with the
optimal rates. The welfare cost is negligible, only .17% of disposable income
for the baseline case and never higher than 2.28% across all values of R and e.
(The welfare cost is zero in the utilitarian case, e 0, since that is equivalent
to a one-consumer economy and the Stone±Geary utility function satisWes the
suYcient condition for uniform taxation to be optimal in the one-consumer
model.)
MANY-PERSON ECONOMY WITH GENERAL TECHNOLOGY
Synthesizing the separate analyses of a one-person economy with general
technology and the many-person economy with linear technology (constant
producer prices) is relatively straightforward, especially under the assump-
tion of CRS production.
Let us begin by considering the optimal commodity tax problem. We saw
that assuming CRS in the context of a one-consumer economy generates the
same optimal tax rules that result when production technology is character-
ized by Wxed producer prices. The key to this result is that there can never be
pure economic proWts or losses under CRS and perfect competition, so that
the value of the general equilibrium proWt function p(
~
p) is identically zero for
all values of the producer price vector
~
p.
The same correspondence exists in the many-person economy. As long as
we assume CRS, the original distribution of lump-sum incomes (I
1
, ...,I
H
)
remains unchanged as producer prices vary in response to taxation. Hence,
the many-person optimal tax rule is identical to its linear technology coun-
terpart. In fact, Diamond used a general-technology CRS model to generate
the many-person optimal tax rules.
A model appropriate for analyzing second-best tax (and expenditure)
problems in a many-person, general-technology economy has four compon-
ents: the social welfare function, consumer preferences, a general production
technology, and market clearance.
Social Welfare and Preferences
The object of government policy is to maximize a social welfare function
of the form:
WV
h
~
q; I
h
V
~
q; I
1
, ...,I
H
speciWed in terms of consumer prices, exactly as in the many-person, linear-
technology case. (We drop the * on W here.)
474 MANY-PERSON ECONOMY WITH GENERAL TECHNOLOGY
Production Technology
Production must be speciWed in terms of prices and actual general equi-
libria to be compatible with social welfare. The speciWcation must also be
Xexible enough to allow for various kinds of technologies. But the general
technology production can no longer be speciWed by means of the generalized
proWt function, p(
~
p), as in the one-consumer economy, because social welfare
is not measured in terms of lump-sum income. Instead, the natural choice is
to return to an implicit aggregate production frontier of the form F(
~
Y) 0,
as in Wrst-best analysis, where
~
Y the vector of aggregate goods supplies
(factor demands). Then, replace the quantities
~
Y with the general equilibrium
market supply (input demand) functions Y
i
Y
i
(
~
p), i 1, ..., N (the same
functions that would result from a social planner maximizing aggregate
proWts at given competitive prices). The resulting function, F[
~
Y(
~
p)] 0,
which is called the production-price frontier, speciWes all relevant production
parameters assuming competitive market behavior.
Market Clearance
General technology requires explicit market clearance equations of the
form:
P
H
h1
X
hi
~
p
~
t, I
h
Y
i
(
~
p) i 1, ..., N (14:63)
to solve for the vector of producer prices given a vector of tax rates. All N
market clearance equations apply because the model describes an actual
general equilibrium, not a compensated general equilibrium. The pricing
identities
~
q
~
p
~
t then solve for the vector of consumer prices.
The Model
Thus, a full general equilibrium model useful for analyzing any problem
in the second-best theory of taxation can be represented as:
max
(
~
q,
~
t
,
~
p)
WV
h
~
q;
I
h
hi
s:t: F[
~
Y(
~
p)] 0
P
H
h1
X
hi
~
q; I
h
Y
i
(
~
p) 1, ...,N
q
i
p
i
t
i
i 2, ...,N
q
1
p
1
1t
1
0
As always, setting t
1
0 ensures that the tax vector
~
t changes the vector of
relative consumer and producer prices and thereby generates distortions.
14. THE SECOND-BEST THEORY OF TAXATION WITH GENERAL PRODUCTION 475
Get Public Finance, 2nd Edition now with the O’Reilly learning platform.
O’Reilly members experience books, live events, courses curated by job role, and more from O’Reilly and nearly 200 top publishers.